"How can I know what I think until I read what I write?" – Henry James
viernes, 13 de mayo de 2016
Más pero no mejor, sobre China
Melancolía de dos años de desgaste perdidos
jueves, 12 de mayo de 2016
Monetizando deuda. Un debate. EEUU versus Europe
If QE doesn’t increase the net worth of the private sector then what does it do? The main effect of QE is in the way it alters the composition of outstanding financial assets. The reduction of the supply of US government bonds puts downward pressure on interest rates by increasing the demand for other bonds. This can result in price increases (what’s commonly referred to as the “wealth effect”) and a portfolio rebalancing which may or may not lead to an indirect increase in private sector net worth. The interest rate channel can also help to stimulate investment by helping to maintain an accommodative interest rate structure. This can also directly impact carry trades through the way financial intermediaries borrow in one currency to finance investment in a different currency. This has been cited as a potential cause of the boom in some emerging market economies in recent years.
Will QE and an expansion of the monetary base lead to more lending? One of the more common beliefs regarding QE is that an expansion of the monetary base will eventually lead to an explosion in loans as banks “lend out” reserves to the public. The problem with this theory, is that banks don’t lend out reserves so more reserves doesn’t necessarily mean more lending. Loans create deposits and banks can obtain reserves from the central bank after the fact. In other words, bank lending is not constrained by the current level of reserves. Therefore, more reserves does not lead to more lending unless there is an increase in demand for loans from creditworthy customers. The money multiplier that we all learn in school is a myth. This is why QE1 and QE2 did not cause a surge in loans or inflation. Lending is a function of demand for debt from creditworthy borrowers.
I’m a bit more skeptical. Hyperinflation, like a stock-market crash or a bank run, is a phenomenon that depends crucially on people’s expectations of what other people will do. If everyone thinks that no one else will spend their dollars, inflation stays low. But if some people start to believe that other folks are about to go out and spend their stockpiles of cash, they will respond by doing the same, so they can buy things before prices start to rise. That will turn inflation into a self-fulfilling prophecy. And just as with bank runs and stock market crashes, we know that expectations can shift very quickly and catastrophically. Hyperinflation is like a bank run on a national currency.
So although the danger of hyperinflation looks very remote for now, a President Trump might change that. If he successfully pressured the Fed to start supporting infinite government borrowing, expectations might suddenly snap, and hyperinflation could result. It’s a risk I’d rather the U.S. didn’t take.
miércoles, 11 de mayo de 2016
Motivos para no estar contentos, de Dean Baker
Yes, the economy is rigged, contrary to what some economists try to tell you
I see Greg Mankiw used his NYT column to tell folks that politicians are spinning tales when they say the economy is rigged. I would say that economists spin tales when they tell you it is not. (Mankiw and I just ran through this argument on a panel in Boston last week.) Let’s quickly run through the main points.
First, the overall level of employment is a political decision. We would have many more people employed today if the deficit hawks had not seized control of fiscal policy back in 2011 and turned the dial toward austerity. The beneficiaries of higher employment are disproportionately those at the middle and bottom of the income distribution: people with less education and African Americans and Hispanics. So the politicians pushing austerity decided that millions of people at the middle and bottom would not have jobs.
Furthermore, in a weaker labor market, it is harder for those at the middle and bottom to get pay increases. So the shift to austerity also meant that tens of millions of workers would have to work for lower pay. Read all about it in my book with Jared Bernstein (free, and worth it).
The second way in which it is rigged is our trade policy. First there is the size of the trade deficit. This is the result of policy choices. Instead of forcing our trading partners to respect Bill Gates copyrights and Pfizer’s patents, we could have insisted they raise the value of their currency to move towards more balanced trade. But Bill Gates and Pfizer have more power in setting trade policy than ordinary workers.
Also, contrary to what Mankiw tries to tell folks in his column, the trade deficit did play a big role in our loss of manufacturing jobs. As my favorite graph for the day shows, manufacturing employment was roughly constant at around 17,500 million from the late 1960s until 2000. During this period, there was substantial growth in manufacturing productivity, as Mankiw says. This growth caused manufacturing employment to decline as a share of total employment, but to remain roughly constant in absolute terms.
Manufacturing Employment
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
However, from 2000 to 2006 manufacturing employment falls by more than 3 million, or close to 20 percent. The change was the explosion in the size of the trade deficit, as an over-valued dollar made our goods less competitive. This plunge in employment devastated lives and whole communities. It was a clear policy choice. Importers like Walmart and outsourcers like GE benefited, as ordinary workers lost big-time.
In addition to the volume of trade flows, there is also the content. We could be importing doctors, dentists, lawyers, and other highly trained professionals. This would mean writing trade agreements that made it as easy as possible for smart kids in foreign countries to train to our standards in these areas and then to work freely in the United States, just like people born in New York or California.
This would have lowered the wages of the most highly paid workers and reduced the prices that the rest of us have to pay for health care, dental work, and other high-priced professional services. We didn’t go this route because highly paid professionals have more power than autoworkers and textile workers. (Yes, we can compensate developing countries so that they can train 2–3 professionals for every one that comes here — please don’t show your ignorance by arguing the opposite in a comment.)
Then we have the financial sector. This has many of the richest people in the country who make their money fleecing the rest of us. It is wrong to say that the sector is deregulated, since it benefits from all sorts of government backstops, as we saw clearly in 2008–2009. We could downsize the sector, making it smaller and more efficient, with a financial transactions tax. Such a tax could free up more than $100 billion a year (@0.6 percent of GDP) for productive uses, while hugely reducing the incomes of the very rich.
Next we come to patent and copyright protection, both government granted monopolies that allow some folks to get very rich by charging the rest of us more money. This is most apparent with prescription drugs. A drug like Sovaldi carries a list price of $84,000 when it would sell in a free market for just a few hundred dollars per treatment. This rigging reflects the political power of the pharmaceutical, software, and entertainment industry. (Yes, there are other ways to finance drug development and creative work.)
Then we get to our broken corporate governance process that allows even failed CEOs like Carly Fiorina to walk away with over $100 million. The problem is that CEO pay is largely determined by their friends on the boards of directors. It is not determined by people who are asking whether they could get as good a CEO for less money. (Why try to take money from your friend?)
In Europe and Japan, CEOs are also well-paid, but they tend to get a third or a quarter of what our CEOs earn. This matters not only because of the pay the CEOs get, but also because of its impact on pay structures throughout the economy. It is now common to see top executives of non-profit hospitals, universities, or private charities get salaries of more than $1 million a year. They argue that they would get much more working for a corporation of the same size. And, this money comes out of the pockets of the rest of us.
So folks, the economy is rigged — better to believe the politicians than the economists.
Historia de las ideas económicas. Paul Krugman versus Roger Farmer
Microfoundations and the Parting of the Waters
Neo-Paleo-Keynesianism: A suggested definition
¿Y a mí qué si hay vida en otros planetas?
martes, 10 de mayo de 2016
Algunas paradojas y misterios surgidos en la economía post crisis
While acknowledging the risks inherent in a policy approach that excessively decouples financial asset prices from fundamentals, defenders of prolonged reliance on unconventional monetary measures point to three potential mitigating factors: an economic liftoff (also known as the attainment of “escape velocity”), where rapid growth would validate what previously were artificially high asset prices; effective “macro-prudential” measures that contain the spillover from excessive risk taking; and, should both fail, a stronger financial architecture and new tools to clean up the financial mess without much contamination to the real economy. Chair Yellen eloquently spoke to these issues
lunes, 9 de mayo de 2016
Patrón oro, Gran Depresión, proteccionismo
Tampoco es cierto otro error muy común, que fue la hiperinflación la que hundió a Alemania. La hiperinflación se acabó cuando Alemania se adhirió al patrón oro en 1924... Lo que le provocó una gran deflación, una dislocación mucho mayor de su economía. No fue la hiperinflación lo que hizo ganar las eleciomes a Hitler en 1933...
Otra de las versiones trivializadas es la de que fue auge del proteccionismo el causante de la GD. El artículo demuestra que el proteccionismo vino después que la GD.
Este artículo tiene la virtud de colocar cada una de estas versiones parciales en orden correlativo, de modo que se puede apreciar qué fue lo importante y lo que fue subsidiario en la GD. De él selecciono la parte narrativa, obviando la parte empírica que el lector puede seguir en el original.
... What accounts for the cross-country variation in the use of protectionist measures? We argue the exchange rate regime and associated economic policies were key determinants of trade policies in the early 1930s. Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping their currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade. With other countries devaluing and gaining competitiveness at their expense, they resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the balance of payments and limit gold losses. Lacking other instruments, notably an independent monetary policy with which to address the deepening slump, they used trade restrictions to shift demand toward domestic goods and, they hoped, stem the rise in unemployment.
In contrast, countries that abandoned the gold standard, allowing their currencies to depreciate, saw their balances of payments strengthen. They gained gold rather than losing it. Abandoning the gold standard also freed up monetary policy. With no gold parity to defend, interest rates could be cut. No longer constrained by the gold standard, central banks had more freedom to act as lenders of last resort. Because they possessed other policy instruments with which to ameliorate the Depression, they were not forced to resort to trade protection as a second-best macroeconomic tool...
... Unfortunately, the interwar gold-exchange standard was less robust than its prewar predecessor. Governments largely resurrected the prewar pattern of exchange rates despite the fact that relative financial strength and competitive positions had changed as a result of the war. Old gold parities were restored without lowering price levels to prewar levels, resulting in a lower ratio of the value of gold to nominal transactions. The remaining gold was unevenly distributed, with some 60 per cent in the hands of the United States and France.
While the resulting gold shortage was addressed by encouraging the more widespread use of foreign exchange reserves, this heightened the fragility of the system. The willingness of countries to hold foreign exchange was only as strong as the commitment of the reserve-center countries, the United States and Britain, to honor their commitments to convert their liabilities into gold at a fixed price. If those commitments were called into question, there might be a scramble out of foreign exchange, putting sharp deflationary pressure on the world economy And the credibility of those commitments was now less than before World War I. Whether central banks would subordinate other objectives to defending their gold parities was called into question by democratization, the rise of trade unions, and growing awareness of the problem of unemployment. If they wished to maintain investor confidence, central banks could not now show any inclination to deviate from the gold standard rules.
Finally, the international cooperation that had helped to support the prewar system, allowing countries in crisis to continue to adhere to gold parities, was more difficult in the aftermath of a war that had bequeathed ill will, war debts, and reparations.
For all these reasons, the interwar gold standard was incapable of withstanding the shock of the Great Depression.5 The system immediately came under strain with the economic slowdown and recession that began in 1928-29. The trigger for this downturn continues to be debated, although recent accounts have highlighted the decision by the Federal Reserve Board to tighten monetary policy and the French decisions to de jure stabilize the franc at a depreciated rate and to convert holdings of foreign exchange reserves into gold, all in 1928 (Hamilton 1987, Eichengreen 1992, Johnson 1997). These policies drained gold from the rest of the world and required other countries to pursue more restrictive monetary policies.
The spark that caused the world trading system to collapse was the financial crisis in the summer of 1931.11 The failure of the largest Austrian bank, the Creditanstalt, unsettled financial markets and caused capital flows to seize up. The German government depended on foreign loans to finance its expenditures, and the drying up of those loans triggered a run on the mark and a loss of gold reserves (Ferguson and Temin 2003, Temin 2008). The government was forced to impose strict controls on foreign exchange transactions. In theory Germany could have devalued, but the reparations agreement fixed its obligation in dollars of constant gold content. This meant that devaluing would have had devastating effects on the public finances. In any case memories of hyperinflation when the gold standard was in abeyance meant that abandoning the system would have unleashed a collective hysteria.12 To limit losses of gold and foreign exchange reserves, Germany therefore imposed controls on capital movements as well as trade finance. Hungary was hit, since its financial system was tied to Austria’s; it imposed controls in July 1931. Other countries such as Chile, which was battered by declining copper prices, followed with controls of their own...
... In August the pressure spread to Britain as trade credits extended to Germany by British merchant banks were frozen.13 A sharp increase in interest rates did little to stem the Bank of England’s gold losses. Against the backdrop of rising unemployment which rendered the Bank reluctant to raise interest rates further, the need for lender-of-last-resort intervention now tipped the balance. On September 19, Britain abandoned the gold standard and allowed sterling to depreciate.
That depreciation sent shockwaves through the world economy. Other countries either followed Britain off gold or imposed restrictions on trade and payments as a defensive measure to reduce imports and strengthen the balance of payments. Within days, other countries with close trade and financial ties to Britain -- Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden among them - - allowed their currencies to depreciate relative to gold. Japan, concluding that its recent resumption of gold convertibility had been a mistake, followed in December...
... Thus, in the midst of the global depression, countries that remained on the gold standard sought to improve their balance of payments position and preserve their gold and foreign exchange reserves. This could be achieved either by limiting capital exports through exchange controls (Germany) or by limiting spending on imports through trade restrictions (France), or both. In fact, such policies were substitute for one another. If exchange controls were comprehensive, they could be administered in a manner that left no need for additional measures such as tariffs or quotas. Import licensing and government allocation of foreign exchange meant that officials could determine the total amount of spending on imports and allocate that spending across different goods and country suppliers. Therefore, a country imposing exchange controls might not have to resort to higher tariffs and quotas because it already had the ability to limit imports through administrative action....
... If countries remaining on the gold standard raised trade barriers as a result of their inability to resort to other more conventional policies to stabilize their economies and financial systems, it follows that countries should have begun relaxing their trade restrictions once they abandoned gold. There is evidence of this. In 1934, a year after the United States went off gold, Congress enacted the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act authorizing the president to reduce U.S. import duties in trade agreements with other countries. Within four years, the agreements reached under the act had essentially undone the Smoot-Hawley tariff increase (Irwin 1998).
Similarly, once the remaining gold bloc countries devalued in September 1936 and started recovering from the slump, they began removing some of their trade barriers. League of Nations (1942, 85) noted that “Before the end of October 1936, tariff reductions and/or quota relaxations had been announced in France, Switzerland, the Netherlands, Italy, Czechoslovakia, and Latvia.” For example, having devalued in September, France reduced its tariffs by 15-20 per cent the next month, and Switzerland reduced many of its import tariffs by more than 50 per cent.46 Relaxing the gold constraint and pursuing more expansionary monetary policies relieved the pressure to maintain restrictive trade policies. On the other hand, countries imposing exchange controls never formally abandoned the gold standard and consequently continued to restrict trade through such controls for the rest of the decade...
Conclusions
... Our account helps explain why some countries were more inclined than others to a protectionist response and lends structure to the otherwise chaotic tale of the collapse of world trade. It suggests that had more countries been willing to abandon the gold standard and use monetary policy to counter the slump, fewer would have been driven to impose trade restrictions in the desperate if ultimately futile effort to stem the rise in unemployment...